465 0

Full metadata record

DC FieldValueLanguage
dc.contributor.author조인구-
dc.date.accessioned2019-12-01T11:06:32Z-
dc.date.available2019-12-01T11:06:32Z-
dc.date.issued2017-10-
dc.identifier.citationAMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW, v. 107, no. 11, page. 3589-3616en_US
dc.identifier.issn0002-8282-
dc.identifier.issn1944-7981-
dc.identifier.urihttps://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/aer.20160665-
dc.identifier.urihttps://repository.hanyang.ac.kr/handle/20.500.11754/115799-
dc.description.abstractA decision maker doubts the stationarity of his environment. In response, he uses two models, one with time-varying parameters, and another with constant parameters. Forecasts are then based on a Bayesian model averaging strategy, which mixes forecasts from the two models. In reality, structural parameters are constant, but the (unknown) true model features expectational feedback, which the reduced-form models neglect. This feedback permits fears of parameter instability to become self-confirming. Within the context of a standard asset-pricing model, we use the tools of large deviations theory to show that even though the constant parameter model would converge to the rational expectations equilibrium if considered in isolation, the mere presence of an unstable alternative drives it out of consideration.en_US
dc.description.sponsorshipWe thank Mikhail Anufriev, Jaroslav Borovicka, Jim Bullard, George Evans, Lars Hansen, Seppo Honkapohja, Albert Marcet, Tom Sargent, and Noah Williams for helpful comments and discussions. We are especially grateful to four anonymous referees for many constructive comments and suggestions. Shirley Xia provided expert research assistance. The first author gratefully acknowledges financial support from the National Science Foundation and the Korea Research Foundation (2015S1A5A2A01011999). The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the National Science Foundation, Korea Research Foundation, the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors. The authors declare that they have no relevant or material financial interests that relate to the research described in this paper.en_US
dc.language.isoen_USen_US
dc.publisherAMER ECONOMIC ASSOCen_US
dc.subjectLARGE DEVIATIONSen_US
dc.subjectNASH EQUILIBRIUMen_US
dc.subjectSTOCK-MARKETen_US
dc.subjectLONG-RUNen_US
dc.subjectUNCERTAINTYen_US
dc.subjectVOLATILITYen_US
dc.subjectFORECASTSen_US
dc.titleGresham's Law of Model Averagingen_US
dc.typeArticleen_US
dc.relation.no99(3)-
dc.relation.page279-294-
dc.relation.journalAMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW-
dc.contributor.googleauthorCho, In-Koo-
dc.contributor.googleauthorKasa, Kenneth-
dc.relation.code2017015981-
dc.sector.campusS-
dc.sector.daehakCOLLEGE OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE[S]-
dc.sector.departmentDIVISION OF ECONOMICS & FINANCE-
dc.identifier.pidinkoocho-
Appears in Collections:
COLLEGE OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE[S](경제금융대학) > ECONOMICS & FINANCE(경제금융학부) > Articles
Files in This Item:
There are no files associated with this item.
Export
RIS (EndNote)
XLS (Excel)
XML


qrcode

Items in DSpace are protected by copyright, with all rights reserved, unless otherwise indicated.

BROWSE